While in a simplified theory money appears
to be a veil and a mere convenience for transactions, nuanced thinking in the
matter suggests that money affects the real economy in a very profound way.
At the heart of the matter is the question
of redistribution. The presence and persistent use of money in the economy
continuously redistributes wealth/purchasing power. Thus monetary economics has
an important political underpinning.
There is also the matter of focus of a
society. Money through its enabling of financial wealth exerts significant
influence over where the society’s resources are used. There is nothing
rational or implicitly optimal about this resource allocation – contrary to the
dogmatic belief of market theorists. (There is a tautological claim some of
them make – the society gets what it deserves, and within bounds of
feasibility, what it wants and that there is no need to question that. The
problem with this approach is that it generalizes the entire population into a
single organism that can deserve or want things whereas in real life the
political economy is founded upon distinction amongst individuals within the
society.)
Lastly, there is the matter of alteration
in the value systems. While economic theory may choose to remain free from any
commentary on the matters of value systems, it is prudent to note, without
passing a judgment, that value systems of individuals get profoundly shaped by
the idea of money as such (not merely as a means to an end.) This in turn
reflexively boosts the importance of money in the society. If the aim of
economics is welfare, this aspect cannot be ignored. Excessive centralization
of our monetary selves into our personality is probably not utility-optimal. In
other words, obsession with money for the sake of itself it distorting the way
we lead our lives so much that collectively we are probably worse off. A long
term aim of policy should then also be to decentralize money from people’s
lives. This may not be achievable within the narrow toolbox of monetary policy.
However, broader policy framework can use the ‘nudge’ approach to help people
realize more diverse aspects of their being and lead more fulfilling lives.
This may sound revolting to the opponents of ‘big brother’ or ‘soft
paternalism’. However if drug rehabilitation is an acceptable agenda for the
state, the monetary rehabilitation is not very different in principle.
Review
of neoclassical position on money and its limitations
It is logical to expect that a small group
of people transacting among themselves will not be subject to money illusion. Say,
5 people are trading just one good amongst themselves and have differing
‘income’ levels in a toy economy. Suddenly if everyone’s income were to be
doubled, the price of the good might have a tendency to double as well. Most
neoclassical economists take this simplistic notion too far and declare that
there is no money illusion in the real economy as well. Whereas interestingly
enough, even in a laboratory experiment, we might be able to detect deviations
from fully rational behavior as people take time to get used to the new state
of affairs and sometimes do not get used to it at all.
For example, some of them might suddenly
decide to start saving. Some others may not want to increase price because of
reasons of fairness. Still others may expect the incomes to go back to lower
levels and hence play safe. Lack of knowledge, anchoring biases, fairness
considerations, uncertainty will all contribute to people avoiding the jump to
the doubling of price.
I am reasonably certain that even in the
set-ups where knowledge is universal and available (all 5 are told that their
incomes have exactly doubled simultaneously) and uncertainty is removed (they
are also told that these doubled incomes are permanent and will not reduce), we
will still not see the adjustment to double price for a while, and maybe never.
In the real life where below practical
deviations occur, this is even more unlikely.
- Incomes do not rise in tandem. There is differential growth rate across sectors as a norm.
- Tendency to save is almost an exogenous variable in this picture. Income growth rate and consumption growth rate may deviate.
- There are lots of different goods and services. The prices do not respond uniformly. Averaging camouflages this divergent response.
- Consumers do not adjust their reactions to prices in real time. They react differently to different price increases.
Hence the expectation of prices going up
uniformly in line with nominal incomes is a mirage. Of course in a closed
economy, since total expenditure has to be equal to total incomes, the increase
in nominal incomes will lead to rise in the total value of expenditure – price
into volume. If the volume has not grown, prices will grow such that the totals
match. The point however is what goes on below the surface, inside the averages
and aggregates. The simplifying assumption of neoclassical economics is that
everything is uniform. Since things are dealt with either at a single
individual/firm level or only in complete economy-wide aggregates, the implicit
hypothesis is that everything moves in tandem. On pointing out this extreme
assumption, most supporters of the neoclassical theory would say that this is
at best a model and we can always refine it using specific phenomena to
incorporate the deviations.
That misses the whole point. Starting with
a wrong model and theory and then trying to get closer to reality through
refinements is likely to be epistemologically wrong. What is worse, it is
likely to throw up fairly misleading policy prescriptions.
The model is oversimplified but that can be
ignored since refinements will tide over that limitation. A bigger issue is
that the model incorrectly models economic participants as REAs with complete
knowledge and fully calculated rational responses. This is an assumption that
cannot be improved incrementally through incorporating one behavioral bias at a
time and one incomplete information point at a time. Wondering about this one
comes to a more fundamental question – why do we need to cling to the
neoclassical model and then refine it? Why can’t we think of a new model which
also models reality but starts with more real assumptions and is likely to need
less refinement to achieve the same outcome as regards predictions and recommendations?
At the heart of it, the debate boils down to the modus operandi of conducting
studies in macroeconomics. There is no right approach. The limitations of the
neoclassical model seem to suggest that there is probably a much better way of
modeling macroeconomic reality.
No comments:
Post a Comment